5. 總結(jié)
本文嘗試了整合技術(shù)、國(guó)際貿(mào)易和全球價(jià)值鏈文獻(xiàn),并基于當(dāng)下全球化、生產(chǎn)活動(dòng)碎片化和無(wú)形資產(chǎn)貿(mào)易增長(zhǎng)的趨勢(shì)發(fā)展出一套整合了產(chǎn)品貿(mào)易和無(wú)形資產(chǎn)貿(mào)易的國(guó)際貿(mào)易分析框架。通過深入討論五種無(wú)形資產(chǎn)貿(mào)易的模式,本文發(fā)展出一套基于全球價(jià)值鏈的國(guó)際貿(mào)易統(tǒng)計(jì)框架。把這個(gè)框架應(yīng)用于美國(guó)貿(mào)易收支計(jì)算,我們發(fā)現(xiàn)考慮無(wú)形資產(chǎn)貿(mào)易后, 2016年美國(guó)的貿(mào)易凈收支(包括產(chǎn)品、知識(shí)產(chǎn)權(quán)、保險(xiǎn)和金融服務(wù)、計(jì)算機(jī)通訊和其他服務(wù),以2%收益率和總OFDI和無(wú)形資產(chǎn)密集行業(yè)FDI歷史存量計(jì)算的無(wú)形資產(chǎn)凈收益,以及蘋果公司的非美國(guó)部分收入)為3963.8億美元逆差,比 7499.3億美元僅以產(chǎn)品貿(mào)易計(jì)算的逆差減少了近一半;2015年美國(guó)貿(mào)易凈收支為3971.5億美元逆差,而不是7625.7億美元。如果我們進(jìn)一步加入除蘋果公司外的包含在外包中的無(wú)形資產(chǎn)貿(mào)易,美國(guó)的貿(mào)易逆差應(yīng)當(dāng)更小。因此,本文認(rèn)為國(guó)際貿(mào)易不平衡與相應(yīng)的政策措施應(yīng)當(dāng)基于完整的包括21世紀(jì)多種貿(mào)易活動(dòng)在內(nèi)的統(tǒng)計(jì)框架來(lái)討論。
本文的貿(mào)易統(tǒng)計(jì)框架提供了一種幫助我們理解21世紀(jì)更廣的貿(mào)易圖景的方法。產(chǎn)品貿(mào)易,甚至產(chǎn)品加服務(wù)貿(mào)易,不再是描述貿(mào)易關(guān)系的好的指標(biāo)。無(wú)形資產(chǎn)貿(mào)易的各種模式和渠道需要被納入到這個(gè)大的貿(mào)易圖景中來(lái)。一種可能的解決方法是整合數(shù)字技術(shù)和可靠的公司自申報(bào)系統(tǒng)。比如,我們可以用物聯(lián)網(wǎng)技術(shù)鏈接各種投入和產(chǎn)出,然后用大數(shù)據(jù)技術(shù)對(duì)比不同來(lái)源數(shù)據(jù)的準(zhǔn)確性和可靠性,以及填補(bǔ)中間的數(shù)據(jù)空白。而國(guó)際合作是建立標(biāo)準(zhǔn)和執(zhí)行對(duì)于新框架的使用和數(shù)據(jù)收集的可行性和可靠性的重要保障。
本文的研究具有重要的政策意義。第一,本文的研究為如何更好的測(cè)度全球化做出了貢獻(xiàn)。全球化不應(yīng)當(dāng)僅僅根據(jù)產(chǎn)品、投資和服務(wù)的互動(dòng)和一體化來(lái)測(cè)度,還應(yīng)該包含追蹤和測(cè)度起來(lái)更加復(fù)雜的無(wú)形資產(chǎn)的流動(dòng)。
第二,本文為全球化的影響的爭(zhēng)論和更包容的全球化政策做出了貢獻(xiàn)。近年,全球化被認(rèn)為是導(dǎo)致發(fā)達(dá)國(guó)家不平等問題的罪魁禍?zhǔn)?。反全球化浪潮出現(xiàn)在一些主流的工業(yè)化國(guó)家。產(chǎn)品的國(guó)際貿(mào)易成為了攻擊對(duì)象。貿(mào)易和投資保護(hù)主義在不斷抬頭。本文的研究表明全球經(jīng)濟(jì)失衡并不像商品貿(mào)易所表現(xiàn)出來(lái)的那么嚴(yán)重。實(shí)際上,工業(yè)化國(guó)家有巨大的無(wú)形資產(chǎn)順差。但是問題是,無(wú)形資產(chǎn)貿(mào)易帶來(lái)的巨大收益集中在少數(shù)的所有者和一小部分創(chuàng)造這些無(wú)形資產(chǎn)的研究技術(shù)人員手里。所以,對(duì)于工業(yè)化國(guó)家來(lái)說,無(wú)形資產(chǎn)貿(mào)易獲得巨大利益的團(tuán)體與社會(huì)其他人群之間的是減少不平等的重要措施。并且應(yīng)當(dāng)禁止跨境避稅行為。
最后,本文的研究對(duì)貿(mào)易不平衡做出了貢獻(xiàn)。我們應(yīng)該從更加整體的角度,從全球價(jià)值鏈的視角來(lái)思考國(guó)際貿(mào)易的問題。解決工業(yè)化國(guó)家(如美國(guó))和發(fā)展中國(guó)家(如中國(guó))之間的貿(mào)易不平衡問題的政策工具應(yīng)當(dāng)是基于真實(shí)的完整的貿(mào)易活動(dòng)。根據(jù)本文的分析,中美真實(shí)的貿(mào)易逆差比大眾認(rèn)知的3570億美元低很多。因此,減少逆差的談判基礎(chǔ)應(yīng)當(dāng)考慮到這個(gè)問題。同時(shí),無(wú)形資產(chǎn)出口應(yīng)當(dāng)被當(dāng)做一種政策工具納入兩國(guó)政府的考量,而不僅僅是高技術(shù)產(chǎn)品的出口。
未來(lái)的研究應(yīng)當(dāng)進(jìn)一步發(fā)展這個(gè)基于全球價(jià)值鏈網(wǎng)絡(luò)的貿(mào)易模型,建立必要的數(shù)據(jù)收集系統(tǒng)、標(biāo)準(zhǔn)和國(guó)際數(shù)據(jù)庫(kù),從主要的全球價(jià)值鏈到所有全球價(jià)值鏈,再到所有類型的全球價(jià)值鏈和不基于全球價(jià)值鏈的貿(mào)易,分析國(guó)家在全球價(jià)值鏈上的位置如何影響他們獲取和分享增加值的能力,分享最近的工業(yè)革命如何快速的改變?nèi)騼r(jià)值鏈的形態(tài)和國(guó)家在其上的位置,以及分析這次工業(yè)革命如何影響國(guó)家間的價(jià)值分配、收入分配、發(fā)展中國(guó)家的升級(jí),還有分析哪些政策制度對(duì)于無(wú)形資產(chǎn)和產(chǎn)品整體貿(mào)易框架的健康運(yùn)行是必要的,最后還有分析IPR保護(hù)的角色和確??煽康?、有益的數(shù)據(jù)產(chǎn)生和分享所需的監(jiān)管。
參考文獻(xiàn)
Alcacer,J., &Oxley, J. (2014). Learning by supplying. Strategic ManagementJournal, 35(2), 204-223.
Antràs, P.,(2003). Firms, Contracts, and Trade Structure. The Quarterly Journal ofEconomics, 118(4), pp.1375-1418.
Balassa, B.,(1986). Intra-industry specialization: a cross-country analysis. EuropeanEconomic Review, 30(1), pp.27-42.
Baldwin,R. E., &Evenett, S. J. (2015). Value creation and trade in 21st centurymanufacturing. Journal of Regional Science, 55(1),31-50.
Baldwin, R. andRobert-Nicoud, F., (2014). Trade-in-goods and trade-in-tasks: An integratingframework. Journal of International Economics, 92(1),pp.51-62.
Baldwin, R., and A. Venables (2013): “Spidersand Snakes: Offshoring and Agglomeration in the Global Economy,” Journal ofInternational Economics, 90 (2), 245–254.
Blinder, A. (2006). Offshoring: The Next IndustrialRevolution? Foreign Affairs, 85(2), 113-128. doi:10.2307/20031915
Constantinescu,I. C., Mattoo, A., Mulabdic, A., &Ruta, M. (2018). Global trade watch 2017: trade defies policy uncertainty - will itlast? (English). Washington, D.C.: World Bank Group. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/934031525380654860/Global-trade-watch-2017-trade-defies-policy-uncertainty-will-it-last
Corrado, C. A.,Haskel, J., Jona Lasinio, C., &Iommi, M. (2012). Intangible capital andgrowth in advanced economies: Measurement and comparative results.Publisher:Imperial College Business School, https://spiral.imperial.ac.uk:8443/handle/10044/1/9913
Gereffi, G., Humphrey, J., &Sturgeon, T. (2005).The governance of global value chains. Review of internationalpolitical economy, 12(1), 78-104.
Grossman, G. M., &Rossi-Hansberg, E. (2012). Tasktrade between similar countries.Econometrica, 80(2),593-629.
Grossman, G.M. and Rossi-Hansberg, E., (2008). Tradingtasks: A Simple Theory Of Offshoring. American Economic Review, 98(5),pp.1978-97.
Guvenen, F., Mataloni, R. J., Rassier, D. G., Ruhl, K.J. (2018) ‘Offshore Profit Shifting and Domestic Productivity Measurement’,NBER Working Paper No. 23324.
Haskel, J.,& Westlake, S. (2017). Capitalism without Capital: The Rise of theIntangible Economy. Princeton University Press, Princeton and Oxford.
IMF (2017).Balance of Payment Statistics Yearbook: 2017,International Monetary Fund.
Helpman, E., Krugman, P., 1985.Market Structure and Foreign Trade. MITPress, Cambridge, MA.
Kaplinsky, R.(2000). Globalisation and unequalisation: What can be learned from value chainanalysis? Journal of development studies, 37(2),117-146.
Krugman, P.(1991). Increasing returns and economic geography. Journal of politicaleconomy, 99(3), 483-499.
Krugman, P.R.,1981. Intra-industry Specialization and the Gains from Trade. Journalof Political Economy, 89(5), pp.959-973.
Krugman, P. R.(1979). Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and internationaltrade. Journal of international Economics, 9(4),469-479.
Krugman,P., Cooper, R. N., &Srinivasan, T. N. (1995). Growing world trade: causesand consequences. Brookings papers on economic activity, 1995(1),327-377.
Lancaster, K.,(1980). Intra-industry Trade Under Perfect Monopolistic Competition. Journalof International Economics, 10(2), pp.151-175.
Leamer, E.(1995). The Heckscher-Ohlin Model in Theory and Practice.International Economics Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.
Markusen, J.R.and Venables, A.J., (2000). The theory of endowment, intra-industry andmulti-national trade. Journal of International Economics, 52(2),pp.209-234.
Milberg, W. (2004). The changing structure of tradelinked to global production systems: what are the policy implications? InternationalLabour Review, 143(1‐2), 45-90.
Melitz, M.J.,(2003). The impact of trade on intra‐industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity.Econometrica,71(6), pp.1695-1725.
Moris, F. (2017) Intangibles Trade and MNEs:Supply-Chain Trade in R&D Services and Innovative Subsidiaries, Journal ofIndustry, Competition and Trade, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10842-017-0265-0.
Mu, Q., &Lee, K. (2005). Knowledge diffusion,market segmentation and technological catch-up: The case of the telecommunicationindustry in China. Research policy, 34(6), 759-783.
Mudambi, R. (2008). Location, control and innovationin knowledge-intensive industries. Journalof economic Geography, 8(5), 699-725.
OECD(2013). Interconnected Economies: Benefiting from Global Value Chains.OECD Publishing.
OECD.(2017), OECD Science, Technology and Industry Scoreboard 2017: Thedigital transformation, OECD Publishing, Paris, http://dx.doi.org/10.1787/9789264268821-en.
Reinsdorf,M. B. and Slaughter, M. J. (2009) InternationalTrade in Services and Intangibles in the Era of Globalization, Universityof Chicago Press.
Ricardo, D. (1817). On the Principles ofPolitical Economy and Taxation,London: John Murray.
Rodriguez-Clare, A. (2010). Offshoring in a Ricardian world, AmericanEconomic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2 (2).
Rungi,A., &Del Prete, D. (2018). The smile curve at the firm level: Where valueis added along supply chains. EconomicsLetters, 164, 38-42.
Shih, S. (1992).Empowering technology—making your life easier. Acer’s Report, Acer’s, New Taipei.
Shih, S. (1996).Me-Too Is Not My Style: Challenge Difficulties, Break ThroughBottlenecks, Create Values. The Acer Foundation, Taipei.
Smith, A. (1776).An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. London: George Routledge and Sons.
Sturgeon, T. J. (2001). How do we definevalue chains and production networks? IDS bulletin, 32(3),9-18.
UNCTAD. (2018).Key Statistics and Trendsin International Trade: The Status of World Trade 2017.United Nations: New York and Geneva. http://unctad.org/en/pages/PublicationWebflyer.aspx?publicationid=2109
Venables,A.J., (1999). Fragmentation and multinational production. European EconomicReview. 43, 935–945.
Vernon, R. (1966). InternationalInvestment and International Trade in the Product Cycle. The QuarterlyJournal of Economics, 80(2), 190-207.
Walsh, J. P., Lee, Y. N., &Nagaoka,S. (2016). Openness and innovation in the US: Collaboration form, ideageneration and implementation. Research Policy, 45(8),1660-1671.
WIPO (2017).World Intellectual Property Indicators – 2017, WIPO, Switzerland.
World Bank. (2017). World Bank Annual Report 2017 (English). Washington,D.C.: World Bank Group. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/143021506909711004/World-Bank-Annual-Report-2017
附錄
圖 1A. 中美保險(xiǎn)金融服務(wù)和ICT服務(wù)
?。ㄎ恼聛?lái)源:牛津大學(xué)技術(shù)與管理發(fā)展研究中心)
-
大數(shù)據(jù)"坑熟客",技術(shù)之罪需規(guī)則規(guī)避
2018-03-02 08:58:39
-
高質(zhì)量發(fā)展,怎么消除“游離感”?
2018-03-02 08:58:39
-
學(xué)校只剩一名學(xué)生,她卻堅(jiān)守了18年
2018-03-01 14:40:53
-
有重大變動(dòng)!騎共享單車的一定要注意了
2018-03-01 14:40:53
-
2018年,樓市會(huì)有哪些新變化?
2018-03-01 09:01:20